Abstract
An argument is developed for an endogenous development of city-regions throughout the world. Emphasis is placed on seven clusters of tangible regional assets in which investments should preferentially be made. They include basic human needs, organized civil society, the heritage of the built environment and popular culture, intellectual and creative assets, the regions resource endowment, the quality of its environment, and urban infrastructure. In conclusion, a plea is made for a whole of government collaborative approach to planning for an endogenous development.
In one of her earlier books, the recently deceased American-Canadian urbanist Jane Jacobs tells the story of a village named Napizaro several hundred miles to the northwest of Mexico City (Jacobs 1985). Local families had lived there for generations on subsistence farming supplemented by a few cash crops. Their lives, writes Jacobs, were inconceivably grim. But a couple of generations ago, a new factor entered the lives of some of these people: the pull of jobs in the United States. And over the years, Napizaro has come to depend on those jobs for its present prosperity. The community now has street lights, a modern infirmary, and a new bull ring named the North Hollywood in honor of the industrial section of Los Angeles from which this prosperity comes. For the most part today, the villages twelve hundred inhabitants live in comfortable brick houses with pretty patios and TV antennas.
But what you see in Napizaro is less important than what you do not. At any given time, more than three-quarters of the men are away, working in North Hollywood. For all its amenities, Napizaro is described as a sad settlement where leave-takings are sorrowful and absences long, and where women live dreary, lonely lives. Jacobs concludes her story with this observation:
After forty years of remittances, remittances used responsibly, thriftily and cooperatively, the fact remains that if the remittances were to stop, Napizaro would quickly sink back into the grim poverty it knew before the migrations and remittances began. Or more likely, its people would have to abandon the region entirely. For the fact is that despite the money sent back from Los Angeles and the television sets and other imports it buys, economic life in the regionways of making a living right thereremain unchanged (op. cit., 75-78; emphasis supplied).
I would like to take this story, which to me reads like a parable, as my theme for this essay. Only I wont be talking about poor villages in remote parts of the world but of cities and their regions in the rapidly urbanizing countries of the global South. My argument has four parts. First, I want to suggest that we can no longer treat cities apart from the regions surrounding them with which, in multiple ways, they are entwined. Second, I want to critically examine the current policy consensus that a citys future rests chiefly on its exports, and that to achieve such exports, outside capital with its undisputed knowledge of up-to-date technology and global marketing must be invited in to generate the jobs and incomes that are needed. Third, I would like to consider an alternative policy that concentrates on the long-term endogenous development of seven clusters of regional assets that will generate what I consider to be the true wealth of urban-regions. Finally, I will close with some comments on the role of government in promoting such a development.
Cities in Regions: an Organic Relation
We often speak of cities, because the term conveys the general idea of a densely built-up area, but if we are pressed to be more specific, we quickly discover how nebulous the notion of city really is. For some it means a municipality with clearly defined boundaries. For others, it signifies the central business district, the core of a metropolitan area. And how are we to think about the low-density suburbs that surround the urban core and are self-governing? Do they, too, form part of what we mean by the term city? Or how about the airports that bear the name of a central city yet often lie beyond even suburbia in the terrains of the peri-urban? Where shall we say the city ends and the countryside begins? To precisely answer this question is all but impossible, because citiness is a quality that spreads outward from given centers until it begins to intersect with the outer boundaries of adjacent centers, forming a continuous landscape of the urban.
In times past, cities were surrounded by walls that clearly marked their boundary, but the walls have long since gone, and the urban has spilled out into the countryside. Urban water supply is captured in regional watersheds that make the city possible in the first place. Ive already mentioned airports that are located far from the center but are visibly linked to it with rapid transit and expressways. Some of these airports have attracted major multinational investments forming so-called edge or satellite cities on greenfield sites. A good deal of food for the citys population is typically grown in the region and trucked to distribution centers in metropolitan locations. On weekends, masses of people exit from urban and suburban areas to the regional periphery, in the hope of enjoying some moments of leisure in mountain resorts, regional parks, and on beaches.
All this we know from direct observation and experience. The organic relation of city and region is nothing new. But we rarely think of them as an organic unit, especially when the region is itself partitioned into counties, municipalities, and townships. Scholars in both Europe and North America have written extensively about the growing need for a new form of regional governance, but to little avail.[2] City and region remain divided and often compete with each other for global capital. China is the notable exception. Its prefectural cities have been designated as leading cities with authority over adjacent rural counties, thus becoming responsible for a coordinated development. Most of Chinas population today lives in one or another of these city-regions. Therefore, when I speak of cities and regions in the remainder of this essay, what I have in mind is this organic relationship for which city-region is the symbolic expression.
Cities are not containers
Compete or perish, say neo-liberal pundits. The competition, of course, is not for the attention of consumers but for outside investors. The imaginary which has become almost universally accepted is that capital is constantly on the look-out for opportunities to grow more capital, and will go to wherever the prospects of growing capital are the most promising. Global capital is footloose, we are told. It has no loyalty to place, and its horizon of expectation is short: investments have to be recouped within only a few years. What cities must therefore do to attract this footloose capital is to show their willingness to accommodate its hard-core requirements: appropriate economic infrastructure, cheap land, disciplined labor, and tax relief. Following this advice, cities try to make themselves as attractive as possible to global suitors. Turning themselves into virtual commodities for the capital market, they compete for attention by branding their image. They chase after the magic of the Olympics or some other global sporting event, hoping that if they win over competing locations, they will become household words, like Coca-Cola or Nike athletic gear. They prostrate themselves before the power of global corporations, promising to deliver what is wanted of them, from virgin sites to low wages and political stability.
Once a city is successful in luring a promised investment, its emissaries return home to great acclaim. But the city is not simply a container for inbound investments unless it wishes to repeat the fate of Jane Jacobs village Napizaro of which she said, if ever the flow of remittances should cease, it would soon return to its former misery. Because once capital moves on to more promising locations, as it often will, what it leaves behind is little more than the empty shell of abandoned factories. Meanwhile the city will have lost more than just a few hundred or perhaps thousands of jobs. It will have squandered an opportunity to develop its own tangible assets, which in their place-specific qualities are always unique. It will have failed to initiate and sustain an endogenous developmenta development from withinbased chiefly on local savings, supplemented by international aid and private contributions. And it will have lost a chance to learn about how to promote a genuine development by engaging in it directly. I turn now to a consideration of these assets, and why neglecting them engenders a false hope in the shimmering pot of gold at the end of the rainbow.
True wealth: the quality of a citys tangible assets
I divide the tangible assets of city-regions into seven clusters that include human, social, cultural, intellectual, natural, environmental, and urban assets. To varying degrees these assets are present in all city-regions, in rich countries as well as poor, and I shall argue that investing in them should be the principal task of local government.
Heading the list are a citys human assets, that is, people and the quality of their lives and livelihood. At issue here are the so-called basic human needs, principally affordable housing; educational opportunities for both girls and boys to prepare them for the modern world; and access to good health. (There is a fourth basic needaffordable mobilityof which I will speak later). The satisfaction of these tangible, material needs constitutes the foundation for our most fundamental right, which is the right to life. Achieving quality housing, education, and health for every citizen must therefore be the aim of every genuine development. In the final analysis, this is a state responsibility. Leaving their satisfaction to the blind operation of market forces will only create gross inequalities, allowing those few who already have a foundation in basic assets to pursue a life of human flourishing while marginalizing the majority who lack the foundations for this most precious of human rights.
The second regional asset is its organized civil society, that is, the multiple self-organizing activities of local citizens. No list can do justice to the myriad things that people (who are by nature social beings) will do for themselves. There are local churches, mosques, and temples that are supported by and draw the faithful. In some countries, such as China, there are lineage and ancestral associations that link the present generation to generations past. For younger people, there are athletic groups promoting every sort of sport, while others engage in music making and dancing. In Spain, I have come across gastronomic clubs whose members enjoy cooking for each other, celebrating fellowship with food and wine. Others join civic clubs promoting projects throughout the city from neighborhood beautification campaigns to visiting old peoples homes. Hobbies ranging from flower arranging to collecting song birds and crickets will inevitably bring aficionados together. In some western countries, such as Canada, there are also associations, some powerful, some not, that are politically active, lobbying the government on behalf of various causes. And so on.
But in what ways, we might ask, are these associational forms of civic life an asset to be nurtured, particularly at the local level? In some countries, the state regards civil society organizations as a potential threat to the established order. The political class believes that these organizations must be closely supervised or at least monitored, that they are potentially a source of trouble for the state. The truth is that organized civil society is for the most part deeply engaged with the everyday life of neighborhoods and communities. Basketball or soccer teams from different parts of the city-region play against each other and are celebrated as local heroes. Religious associations sponsoring festivals honoring local saints, generate a strong sense of belonging and also support the work of volunteers in the community. Housing associations assist people in acquiring a home. Neighborhood centers help to integrate newcomers into the mainstream of urban life (Attili and Sandercock 2007). Lobbying groups bring their concerns forcefully to the attention of government, pushing for new legislation. Youth clubs help young people who might otherwise be lost to the street find support among their peers. And thus, far from encouraging dreaded chaos, organized civil society should be seen, even when it is a voice of protest, as a source of civic strength, an asset worthy of public support. Its existence acknowledges the full diversity of the city while promoting local citizenship.
The citys heritage of its built environment and the distinctiveness and vibrancy of its cultural life comprise the third cluster of assets. Both are aspects of its collective identity, signifying continuity in time. We usually think of city-regions as being economically defined, and economic relations are certainly important. But equally important is a sense of the region and its major urban centers as something other than a confusing bundle of functional linkages involving goods and people being transported from one location to another. At this deeper level, we tend to think of cities and regions as places that have above all a cultural significance, a history. It is because their historical continuities often reaching far into the past that we care about them, acquiring a sense of ownership and belonging (Friedmann 2006). This sense of belonging can be destroyed, as it has in many African cities (Simone 2004, 2006). But globalization does not make this an inevitable outcome.
One way to strengthen peoples collective identity with their city is by preserving and investing in its heritage. In the vast expanses of the contemporary city, the heritage of the built environment, its fine grain, is of special significance. People identify with their neighborhoods before they identify with the region as a whole, many parts of which they have never visited. Most of us live our lives quite locally, not universally, and we treasure the small spaces of the city, its public markets, neighborhood temples, local tea rooms, coffee shops, and pubs that are places of encounter, or even an entire district such as Kyotos Gion quarter centered upon its famous shrine (Friedmann 2007). In Canadas Vancouver, perhaps the most popular of all public spaces is Granville Island, a remarkable adaptation of an old industrial space into a public market that draws thousands of local shoppers and tourists each day. On the other side of the Pacific, in Chinas southern Fujian Province, the city of Zhangzhou is an example of a small city that values its physical heritage, particularly in the so-called historical block with its memorial archways carefully preserved in harmony with their ever-changing surroundings.
The second part of this cluster is the vibrancy of a citys cultural life. Here I am thinking specifically of certain popular traditions in which people of all ranks and ages participate, which come round each year, and to which everyone looks forward with pleasure. They include festive occasions that mark the passing of the seasons, such as São Joãos Day in the Brazilian city of Salvador, Bahia, with its ancient flower sacrifice to the fishermens goddess, Iemanja, and magical paper balloons that carry flickering lights across the darkening night sky. Or a three-day festival in Tudela, a small city in northern Spain, with dancing on the city square, communal breakfasts on tables set out in the streets, and a religious procession, carrying an image of the Virgin Mary around the neighborhoods of her city. Or celebrating the Dia de los Santos in Mexican barrios. All these popular festivities emerge, as it were, spontaneously, year after year. Local traditions, they are both civic and popular occasions that build bonds of solidarity among the people while strengthening place identity.
The fourth cluster of assets are the citys intellectual and creative assets, which are the quality of its universities and research institutes and what the Japanese call their living human treasures, its master artisans and artists, intellectuals and scientists, and all others, musicians and writers, poets and film makers, actors and dancers who embody a regions creative powers. Small in number, they are nonetheless essential to a regions future and should count among its finest treasures. The best among them are also the rarest, and to lose them would be an inestimable loss to the city. Creativity must be nurtured. It is important to allow these human treasures to exercise their talents to the fullest. Scientists need research laboratories. Students pursuing advanced degrees require universities that are properly equipped and staffed. Film makers require studio spaces and artists need galleries to display their work as well as studios. Actors and dancers must have stages to perform their work. And all of them require the freedom to create as they will without fear of public censorship.
There is much talk today about a so-called creative class that cities should attract (Scott 2006). My argument here is different. Although creativity cannot be commanded, creative work requires public support. Market forces alone will not suffice. New ideas and artistic creations are often unpopular, and those who create tend to march to a different drummer from ordinary people. Cultural and intellectual elites, their presence ensures a citys capacity for innovation. Professional contacts extend across the globe to other cities, and from these exchanges come new ways of seeing and thinking that add to the citys liveliness and vigor. It is these elites that are the primary source of informed critical thinking which can be crucial to charting a citys future.
I turn now to the fifth cluster consisting of a city-regions natural assets, by which I mean its basic resource endowment: farms, watersheds, lakesides and ocean beaches, picturesque landscapes, forests, and fisheries, whose use is both for production and enjoyment. Natural assets are easily squandered through neglect or thoughtless exploitation. Peri-urban areas are critical spaces in resource management precisely because they are the sites where village and city encounter each other and intermingle in a crazy quilt of land uses. The citys appetite for land is voracious, not only for new housing and industrial uses, but also for airports, landfills, power plants, amusement parks, suburban shopping malls and strip developments along major highway routes. What was once a serene landscape of fields and villages can quickly turn into a fractured, fragmented environment that is neither urban nor rural and seems utterly out of control. And yet, the city vitally depends on this natural endowment that will continue to further the quality of its life so long as planning for the rich diversity of regional land uses ensures an harmonious development of its many, often contradictory functions. City and region stand in symbiotic relation, and so long as this relationship is understood and carefully nurtured, both will advance together. Failing this, the citys heedless expansion threatens to destroy the regions natural endowment, generating economic, social, and environmental costs that will ultimately undermine its own development.
Closely related to its natural resource endowment is the sixth cluster of assets that we call environmental, including those qualities of the physical environment that are essential for sustaining life itself: the air we breathe, the water we drink, and the capacity of the land to support human settlement at high densities. I will say little about it, because so much has already been written.[3] But unless we impose what some would call draconian measures, we will eventually drown and perish in our own wastes. Unfortunately, the message hasnt sunk in to the extent that it needs to, and lip service to the environment is more common than rigorously enforcing the standards that we know must be applied. Newly urbanizing regions are often among the worst offenders, and it is precisely during the early period of what some call primitive accumulation that the worst offenses against the environment take place.
The seventh and final asset cluster is the quality of urban infrastructure, which is all the facilities and equipment for transportation, energy, communications, water supply, sewerage, and solid waste disposal that typically swallow up a large portion of a citys capital budget. There is nothing particularly novel about urban infrastructure as an asset. The question is rather what purposes and social groups are served by public works. Consider the question of city roads. They are certainly needed, but are they needed for buses and other public means of transport or to accommodate private automobiles in constantly growing numbers? In short, are they needed to serve the interests of the 20 percent of the population that in the global South constitute the affluent and emerging middle classes or the needs of the great majority of ordinary people for an affordable mobilitya fourth basic need along with housing, education, and healththrough public transit, bicycles, and walking? Affordable mobility that, as it happens, is also ecologically sustainable, is essential for peoples livelihood; six-lane super-highways and complicated, Los Angeles-style cloverleaf intersections are of little use to them.
The importance of ordinary peoples needs for affordable mobility was clearly demonstrated by the experiment with the participatory budget in Porto Alegre in the 1990s where road paving and bus services in outlying city districts was signaled as a matter of high priority by most neighborhood assemblies (Abers 2000). And so it is with other infrastructure projects: is city building to be a 20 or an 80 percent solution?[4] The temptation is to head for the 20 percent, becauseso the argument goesit is the more educated middle class that ensures continued economic progress. And if the middle class prefers private automobiles and other amenities of life, so be it; the needs of ordinary people can always be postponed. But the end result of such a strategy is the bi-polar city of the fortified citadels of the rich and the teeming, over-crowded slums to which the rest of the population is consigned, their needs for affordable housing, education, health, and mobility largely ignored (Davis 2006). São Paulo is emblematic of the polarized city.
The true wealth of a city, as I argue in these pages, will be found in the progressive development of its assets base through a concerted and sustained effort largely from within itself. True wealth is not measured by the growth of regional income alone, a single statistic that hides more than it reveals. Different sorts of hard data are needed to assess the state of a regions asset base, data that must be collected district by district and even neighborhood by neighborhood to reveal significant variations across space. Overall averages are not very useful for devising appropriate policies, let alone for more detailed planning. Each of a regions many assets must be separately assessed on a yearly basis in terms of investments made and the achieved results. Maps showing outcome measures can be produced and shared with a wider public to gain a comprehensive understanding of the existing situation, the results obtained over the past planning period, remaining disparities, and proposed solutions. Creating a public dialogue around shared information of this sort creates a basis for the next round of contemplated actions (Pieterse 2006). All this may be too much to expect of democratic governance, but it is perhaps useful to be reminded of what ideally would be desirable.
Building assets by steadily investing in them will do more for urban and regional development than soliciting investments from global firms into an underdeveloped asset base subject to further degradation. Global capital is indeed highly mobile. Corporate management has no significant stake in the region where its money is being placed; its eyes are principally on shareholder interests rather than on regional wealth creation. Seducing global capital by sacrificing regional assets leads only to an illusory development. It sets up a situation in which eagerly competing city governments will eventually drive down global wages while heading straight for the 20 percent solution with all that this entails.
The role of government and planning
I turn now to my final topic, which is the role of government and the best ways to plan for an endogenous development. To shift from city-marketing to an endogenous strategy that is focused on developing the city-regions tangible assets requires a strong government capable of undertaking major interventions. It also calls for enlightened political leadership that has embraced a vision not geared to an imaginary that comes straight out of Hollywood movies and television. Finally, an endogenous strategy will need the backing of a majority of the citys population whose sustained support is essential to its success.
Opposition is sure to emerge. Critics will ridicule the principles of an endogenous development. They will ask where the money will come from for such an effort if foreign capital is not involved. They will call it a hopeless bootstrapping operation that will trap the city in perpetual poverty, a sinkhole from which there is no escape. Such criticisms, I would argue, fail to grasp the essential part of the story. First, Im not presenting endogenous development as an exclusive strategy. If a city has unique advantages for foreign capital, foreign capital will come. Nor is all capital of the fly-by-night variety, and firms choose to locate their plants overseas for any number of reasons of which profit maximization (calculated over a longer time period) is only one among a number of other objectives, such as gaining entry to new markets. Second, the upgrading of asset qualities will itself stimulate foreign investments that might hesitate to locate plants in a city such as Lagos, Nigeria, with its shocking conditions of everyday life, but might very well consider investing in a city that has a progressive policy of upgrading its economic, social, and environmental infrastructure. Third, local savings can be substantial even in relatively poor economies so long as the government is prepared to impose on itself a stringent fiscal discipline and vigorously combat corruption. Fourth, the capital expenditures needed for an endogenous development may amount to less than one might think. Meeting the basic needs of an 80 percent city will be expensive, but it neednt happen all at once. What is important, rather, is that urban regions mark steady progress year-by-year, especially in sectors of the basic needs economyin housing, education, health, and affordable mobilitythat can be amply documented and made visible to all. Some assets, such as the natural asset base of the region or its physical heritage and cultural vibrancy, require support for and recognition of popular culture as well as good planning and design, but only a relatively low level of public expenditures. Fifth, clear priorities for public investment must be established. Urban and regional development is not a smooth process towards an imaginary equilibrium state. Instead, as Albert Hirschman taught us long ago, it lurches forward from imbalance to imbalance, as different pressure points become activated, forcing an adjustment in policies and budgetary allocations.[5]
In closing, I would like to make a few observations concerning planning for urban development in emerging regions. Land use or more broadly spatial planning has its place in the total scheme of things. But the sort of planning that effectively addresses the seven asset clusters of city-regions cannot be subsumed under a single plan. It will involve public interventions in housing, education, health services, transportation, sanitation, community and cultural affairs, and all the rest in a whole of government approach. And such an approach is possible only if there is broad agreement within local government on a long-term strategic vision. Building a local consensus is only a beginning, however. Beyond the local bureaucracy there are not only the bureaucracies of senior governments and powerful corporate interests that must be brought along but also, and proceeding downwards to the lower echelons of the citys bureaucracy, the regions county and township governments, urban neighborhoods and community-based organizations will all have to be consulted, because it is here that interventions must ultimately come to rest. Realistically, not everyones energies can be harnessed and aligned with the project of development. What is clear, however, is that development planning proceeds through direct communication, a dialogue among all relevant actors, because it is only as a collaborative venture that it can succeed (Healey 2006). No one has the power and knowledge sufficient to carry out such a vast undertaking without getting everyone on board.
Putting the matter this way poses a new challenge for planners, which is to master the art of listening to a multiplicity of voices, in an attempt to understand their different viewpoints and rationalities, especially when they conflict with our own. Writing of Johannesburg, Harrison (2006) puts it well:
planners and city authorities have revealed a strong capacity to engage with the rationalities of the corporate world. They have struggled, however, to deal with the complex, largely hidden network of informal rules, rationalities and desires that structure the lives of ordinary citizens of the city. Yet, an increasing body of evidence suggests that the plans and policies that are able to engage with this hidden network are those which are most likely to have a positive impact on the lives of urban citizens (332).
Planning in this sense is largely a communicative process in which formal plans, maps, and other documents have a part to play but where the written word is less important than direct speech, and where mutual understandings are forged through continuing collaboration. The project at hand is the creation of wealth through investing in a regions tangible assets that, in the longer term, will reduce its dependency on outside capital, helping to make its future more sustainable.
The sustainable city is a possible dream. It means embracing the fact that cities are embedded in their environment on which their future depends. It means engaging local citizens in the common effort by giving them a stake in the future of their city. It means reaching out to other cities, other regions, and strengthening emerging networks. Above all, it means trusting the citys own powers to shape the future that lies ahead.
References
Abers, Rebecca Neara 2000, Inventing Local Democracy: Grassroots Politics in Brazil. Boulder, Colorado: Lynn Rienner.
Attili, Giovanni and Leonie Sandercock 2007, Where Strangers Become Neighbours: The Story of the Collingwood Neighbourhood House and the Integration of Migrants in Vancouver, a 50-minute documentary. Completed 2006. Distributed by the National Film Board of Canada.
Benjamin, Solomon 2000, Governance, Economic Settings and Poverty in Bangalore, Environment & Urbanization, 12:1, 35-56.
Cronon, William 1992, Natures Metropolis: Chicago and the Great West. New York: W.W. Norton.
Davis, Mike 2006, Planet of Slums. London: Verso.
Economy, Elizabeth 2004, The River Runs Black: The Environmental Challenge to Chinas Future. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Friedmann, John 2006, Four Theses in the Study of Chinas Urbanization, International Journal of Urban and Regional Research, 30:2, 440-451.
Friedmann, John 2007, Reflections on Place and Place-Making in the Cities of China, International Journal of Urban and Regional Research, 31:2, forthcoming.
Gandy, Matthew 2006, Planning, Anti-planning and the Infrastructure Crisis Facing Metropolitan Lagos, Urban Studies, 43:2.
Harrison, Philip 2006, On the Edge of Reason: Planning and Urban Futures in Africa, Urban Studies, 43:2.
Healey, Patsy 2006, Urban Complexity and Spatial Strategies: Towards a Relational Planning for Our Times. London: Routledge.
Herrschel, Tassilo and Peter Newman, Governance of City Regions: Planning, Policy and Politics. London: Routledge, 2002.
Hirschman, Albert O. 1971, A Bias for Hope: Essays on Development and Latin America. Yale University Press.
Jacobs, Jane 1985, Cities and the Wealth of Nations: Principles of Economic Life. New York: Vintage Books, 1985.
Keiner, Marco 2005, Planungsinstrumente einer nachhaltigen Raumentwicklung. Innsbrucker Geographische Studien, vol. 35. Geographie Innsbruck Selbstverlag.
Lo, Fu-chen and Yi-qing Xing, eds. 1999,Chinas Sustainable Development Framework: Summary Report. Tokyo: United Nations University/Institute of Advanced Studies.
Pieterse, Edgar 2006, Building with Ruins and Dreams: Some Thoughts on Realising Integrated Urban Development in South Africa through Crisis, Urban Studies, 43:2, 285-304.
Scott, Allen J., ed. 2001, Global City-Regions: Trends, Theory, Policy. Oxford University Press.
Scott, Allen J. 2006, Creative Cities: Conceptual Issues and Policy Questions, Journal of Urban Affairs, 28:1, 1-16.
Simone, AbdouMaliq 2004, For the City yet to Come: Changing Life in Four Cities. Durham, NC: Duke University Press, 2004.
Simone, AbdouMaliq 2006, Pirate Towns: Reworking Social and Symbolic Infrastructures in Johannesburg and Douala, Urban Studies, 43:2, 357- 370.
[1] This paper was given in 2006 as the First UN-HABITAT Award lecture at the Third World Urban Forum in Vancouver, British Columbia (Canada) and appears here in a somewhat revised form. I would like to thank the following for their critical comments on earlier drafts: Leonie Sandercock, Michael Leaf, Haripriya Rangan, Vinay D. Lall, Matti Siemiatycki, and Linda Herrera. The usual caveats apply.
[2] For an overview, see Scott (2001). With an emphasis on inter-city competition, this book is in the mainstream of current thinking. William Cronon (1992) has written the classic historical study of a city region, using Chicago as a case. For a European perspective on city regional governance, a key issue in regional development policy and planning, see Herrschel and Newman (2002).
[3] For a systematic perspective of environmental planning, see Keiner (2005). For a major country study of Chinas serious environmental dilemmas, not all of them originating in cities, see the overview by Economy (2004) and Lo and Xing (1999). Also relevant here are the annual State of the World Reports put out by the Worldwatch Institute.
[4] These percentages are indicative only. If we look at particular cities, we will find a more accurate division between the haves and have nots. For example, Bangalore, the capital of Karnataka State in India, is a city of over 5 million people. In the late 1990s, the city generated an estimated 3000 tons of solid waste, of which little more than 1000 tons were actually collected (Benjamin 2000). One could reasonably assume, therefore, that one-third of the population (those living in the middle class and affluent neighborhoods of the city) is relatively well served, while two-thirds are not. Hence, Bangalore would be a 30 percent city in my language. The story in Lagos, a city with an estimated population of over 10 million people, is different. Lagos is the former capital of Nigeria, but its recent history, writes Matthew Gandy, has been marked by a stark deterioration in quality of life: Over the past 20 years, the city has lost much of its street lighting, its dilapidated road system has become extremely congested, there are no longer regular refuse collections, violent crime has become a determining feature of everyday life and many symbols of civic culture such as libraries and cinemas have largely disappeared. The citys sewerage network is practically non-existent and at least two-thirds of childhood disease is attributable to inadequate access to safe drinking water (Gandy 2006, 372). In my 80 percent city, such conditions would not exist.
[5] The idea of development as a lurching forward from imbalance to imbalance is found in many of Albert O. Hirschmans works. See for example Hirschman (1971).